您的位置: 首页 » 法律资料网 » 法律论文 »

对“劳动争议发生之日”的理解/王荣

作者:法律资料网 时间:2024-07-07 07:27:04  浏览:8949   来源:法律资料网
下载地址: 点击此处下载
对“劳动争议发生之日”的理解

作者:王荣 律师 单位桂林明辩律师事务所,邮箱:lawyer9900@126.com


劳动仲裁时效是劳动争议案件中非常重要的一个法律问题,因为我国对于劳动争议案件实行仲裁前置程序,必须先进行劳动争议仲裁,只有对仲裁裁决不服的,才可以向法院提起诉讼,请求法院维护其合法权利。
我国的劳动仲裁时效(或者叫申诉时效)是10年前颁布的《劳动法》所确定的一项法律制度,但是随着我国劳动用用制度的发展,现在劳动前置程序以及劳动仲裁时效制度已经越来越不适应现实发展变化了。尤其是仲裁时效制度甚至成为劳动者维护自身权利的一个法律障碍。这里除了60日的时间太短以外,另一个非常重要的问题是仲裁时效起算日的问题。
我们在分析仲裁时效时应该了解一下我国劳动仲裁时效制度的发展变化,这样更有利于我们正确理解劳动仲裁时效。
1995年颁布的《劳动法》第八十二条规定:“ 提出仲裁要求的一方应当自劳动争议发生之日起六十日内向劳动争议仲裁委员会提出书面申请。”也就是说,申请劳动仲裁的仲裁时效是劳动争议发生之日60日。实际上1987年8月15日实施的《国营企业劳动争议处理暂行规定》已经确力这样的仲裁时效制度。属该《规定》第十六条规定因履行劳动合同发生的争议,当事人应当从争议发生之日起六十日内,或者从调解不成之日起三十日内,向仲裁委员会提出。
在《劳动法》颁布前,即1993年国务院颁布的《中华人民共和国企业劳动争议处理条例》 第二十三条规定:“ 当事人应当从知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日起六个月内,以书面形式向仲裁委员会申请仲裁”。该《条例》同时也废止了《国营企业劳动争议处理暂行规定》。也就是说,从1993年8月1日到1995年1月1日期间,我国实行的仲裁时效是从当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日起六个月。
在此,简单地将两者相进行比较,我们很容易发现两者有以下几点不同:
1、仲裁时效的期间不同。《劳动法》规定为60日,《企业劳动争议处理条例》规定为6个月。
2、起算日不同。《劳动法》规定的仲裁时效起算日为“劳动争议发生之日”,《企业劳动争议处理条例》规定的起算日为“从当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日”。
3、法律效力不同。《劳动法》是全国人大制定颁布的,属于法律,《企业劳动争议处理条例》是国务院制定颁布的,属于行政法规,两者效力明显不同。
4、颁布实施时间不同。《企业劳动争议处理条例》所确立的仲裁时效是1993年8月1日开始实施的。《劳动法》所确定的仲裁时效制度是1995年1月日开始实施的。按照新法优于旧法的原则,应该以《劳动法》的规定为准。
通过以上比较,我们很容易得出结论,应该以《劳动法》所确立的仲裁时效制度为准。但是在司法实践中,仍然存在理解上的偏差和分歧,给劳动者维护合法权利带来非常大的困难。
对于仲裁时效最通常的理解,就是1995年1月1日起施行《关于贯彻执行〈中华人民共和国劳动法〉若干问题的意见》中规定,即“劳动争议发生之日”是指当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日”。笔者认为这种理解是值得商榷的。
第一,实际上《劳动法》已经将劳动争议仲裁起算日做了修改,即为劳动争议发生之日,而不再是“当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日”。而劳动部的这一解释,却忽视了这一变化。
第二,按照通常理解能力,有三件是并是完全相同的,一是“权利被侵害之日”,二是“知道或者应当知道自己的权利被侵害之日”,三是“侵害人与被侵害人因此发生争之日”。
“权利被侵害”是权利被侵害的客观状态,“知道或者应当知道自己的权利被侵害”是被侵害人对侵害事实的认知状态,而“侵害人与被侵害人因此发生争议”是侵害人基于对权利被侵害事实的认知,进而向侵害人主张权利并与侵害人发生分歧的状态。
所以,很显然“劳动争议发生之日”是不等于“当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日”。在很多情况下,“劳动争议发生之日”是在“当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日”之后。
笔者认为应该将“劳动争议发生之日”理解为“侵害人基于对权利被侵害事实的认知,进而向侵害人主张权利并与侵害人发生分歧之日”,这样才符合《劳动法》的保护弱势群体的立法原则。这样,在劳动仲裁或者诉讼中,如果用人单位认为劳动者提起的仲裁超过了仲裁时效,那应该是用人单位举证,证明双方发生争议的具体时间,以证明劳动者丧失了请求法律强制保护的权利。否则应该以劳动者提出仲裁的时间为双方发生争议之日。当然,劳动者不能无限期限地躺在权利的床上睡觉。按照《民法通则》规定的诉讼试时效,在当事人知道或者应当知道其权利被侵害之日两年内不主张权利的即为过了诉讼时效期间。此时再提起仲裁或者诉讼,不应该得到支持。
所以,笔者在此呼吁在《劳动法》尚未作出修改前,劳动保障部应该修改其《关于贯彻执行〈中华人民共和国劳动法〉若干问题的意见》中有关劳动争议仲裁时效的条款,以保护劳动者的合法权利。


下载地址: 点击此处下载

Student:Dayong Zhou

dayong_77@hotmail.com


The Collectivizationa and De-collectivization in Rural China

周大勇 (Zhou,Dayong)

Abstract: the process of de-collectivization took place 25 years ago, however it was uncompleted, which determined that china has to make great effort to continue his rural reform, in order to liberate the peasant and the status of rural region as the Party promised. In China, the non-privatization reform occurred along with the de-collectivization was a uncompleted reform, which remains the defects of both collectivization and small-scale peasant economy, therefore it restricts the development of the rural society, however, the current system seems unable also reluctantly to change it. This paper intents to introduce the process of the collectivization and the most important rural reform in this century, namely the de-collectivization, the demonstrates the progression of de-collectivization, its characters as well as the problems left to be solve.
Keywords: collectivization De-collectivization collective ownership incomplete

Foreword
I am pleased that I am allowed to write the term paper about China. China was influenced by Marxism and walked in detour of history for half century. Before Marxism bankrupted in former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe countries, China had adopted a different way to reform from those countries. Because of the difference in aspects of historical evolution, political forms and natural environment, it’s hard to compare the rural society of China with these former socialism countries directly, also, the progression of collectivization and its end are different in two continents.
Rural china before collectivization
Collectivization was a mark system of the socialist state. Although in the era of Utopian socialism, Robert Owen for example has already attempted to set up the collective farm, but it wasn’t pursued by force strength of government. Even the founder of communism Marx didn’t agree that communism could be realized in undeveloped countries with extremely poor productivity . It was Russia, the serf country, in which Communist took power without adequate preparation; collectivization was implemented by force, in order to consolidate the rule in grass-root countryside. This experience has influenced China and Eastern Europe, because one of the merits of the collectivization lies in being easy to be managed, the other lies in being easy to deprive peasants.
China was a backward country, which suffered from ignorance and war for centuries. Throughout the centuries some 80 to 90 percent of the Chinese population were farmers and live in one of some 900,000 villages, which have an average population of from 1,000 to 2,000 people. Villages were not self-contained, self-sufficient units. Clusters of villages centered on small market towns, which linked them to the wider economy and society by providing not only opportunities to buy and sell but also opportunities for entertainment, information, social life, and a host of specialized services. The traditional Chinese elite, often referred to in English as the gentry dispersed across the country and often lived in rural areas, where they were the dominant figures on the local scene, normally ruled villages. Although they held land, which they rented to tenant farmers, they neither possessed large estates like European nobles nor held hereditary titles. However, they traditionally interpreted central policies and national values for villagers. As in feudal relationship, the peasants and gentry live depend on each other. Gentry provided land to poor peasants and tenant, and work with rich and middle peasants to secure the order in village, for instance opening school and building basic infrastructures to maintain there social status. In Chinese history, at the beginning of very dynasty, the land relationship between landlord and poor peasants were comparably fair, that meant, peasant have parcel farmland to live on. But land tended to be concentrated on end every dynasty, then there might be a peasant uprising led to a new dynasty and retribution of land. This is the basic clue of social evolution in China before communist period.
After the Chinese Communist Party came into power in mainland, it had to keep its promise, which it made during the period of war to encourage the peasant to join the army, that it would gave peasant their own land. The first major action took place from 1940s to early 1950s. June 1950, a new Land Reform Law of new People’s Republic was promulgated and stipulated nullification of the feudal land ownership system, and institutionalization of the system of land ownership by peasants, in which the Party sent agents to every village to carry out the land reform policy. This in itself was an unprecedented show of political power and the resolution of transform an old society. The reform was successful, because the peasants supported the policy; most of them had been waiting for the reform for long time. In the light of the reform law, land were redistribute from the landlords, land-owning trusts or wealthier families to the poor segments in the same village; village elites, who might be expected to go up against the Party and its programs were brought down; new leadership was established by poor peasants who showed the most loyalty to the party's goals; instead of kinship group or patron-client ties, class status became new relationship among villagers.
the process of Collectivization
However, the Party’s leaders were not satisfied with the privatization of land, at one hand, such ownership, according to the doctrine of socialism, should have been abolished in the state of socialism, at another hand, private ownership of small peasantry had no function of property accumulation for the country. At that time, in order to accelerate the construction of socialism, China had launched The First Five-Year Plan after the Soviet model; heavy industry development was profound stressed since the leaders of Communist Party regard socialist country as a country with developed industry sectors. However, the situation in early 1950s was not ideal for a new country. Pressing of needs for food in a country with burgeoning population, domestic capital for investment, and purchase of Soviet-supplied technology, capital equipment, and military hardware. To satisfy these needs, collectivize agriculture was put forward. Collectivization was regard as a method to turn countryside to stabile backing, which can be managed as semi-military and had rare contact with outside, so that the government could press the price of agricultural products by means of scissors difference between cities and countryside, and seize huge numbers of profit from agriculture economies to support the industrialization in city. At the same time, the government had already nationalized banking, industry, and even trade. Private enterprise was already virtually abolished in national wide.
Despite internal disagreement as to the speed of collectivization, preliminary collectivization was launched since 1952. China's peasantry saw Chairman Mao and the Communist Party as heroic much more than Russia's peasantry had seen Stalin and the Bolsheviks as heroes, and through 1956 the peasantry cooperated with the Party. There was none of the resistance and warfare that had accompanied the collectivization of agriculture in the Soviet Union.
The collectivization of agriculture was basically completed with the establishment of the people's communes in 1958. The People’s Commune system was defined as a unity of politics and production, in which all members of the commune jointly owned property. Essentially, the commune system was based on private contract of its members and the principle of voluntaries and mutual benefit, however, it turned out yet as coercive institutional arrangement, which was made by government with political power. In the movement to achieve the People’ s Commune, peasants had no choice whether or not to join.
Communes were designed as large, embracing scores of villages created by combining some 20 or 30 advanced producers' cooperatives of 20,000 to 30,000 members on average, in some cases the membership varied from as few as 6,000 to over 40,000. It was instituted as an organization with functions of the lowest level of local government and the highest level of organization in agricultural production. Communes consisted of three organizational levels: the central commune administration; the production brigade , and the production team, which generally consisted of around thirty families. This kind of institution was an organization of hierarchies, in which the commune acted as political unit and top manager, the brigades played role of co-coordinators between the commune and the basic production teams. The production team was basic units of production and accounting. Since the people’s commune system was a tool established to extract resources from agriculture sector for industrialization, as a result, it neglected peasants’ incentive completely. In order to let the people’s commune system run, the central government designed an relative effective mechanism to encourage managers in each hierarchy to work enthusiastically, yet, in each level, the managers were treated differently and there was a clear difference in aspects of identity and welfare between the managers of the commune and of the brigades or production teams.
The commune was defined as administrative organ and executed the central government’s orders, and paid from central government’s budget, therefore the managers in the level of commune were “state cadres” , that means they were formal governmental officials and got wage monthly. These state cadres could be promoted and became officials of governmental divisions in higher level. Brigades and production teams were collective economic organizations, their running expenses came from production teams’ tribute. Managers in brigades level were called “collective cadres” . They were remunerated in their own production teams according to their labor quotas. Their wage was paid in the form of products instead of money. Managers in production teams were“team cadres”, they were also members of the production team. They worked as peasant like their workmates, and were paid in products according to labor quotas. Team cadres could be promoted to collective cadres. Collective and team cadres had little possibilities to be promoted and became members of state cadres. Nevertheless, as collective and team cadres had some privileges. For example, collective managers had the power of assigning state’s delivery quotas and production tasks among production teams, they determined who could enrolled in state-owned factories, universities and army. The production team managers executed the power of assigning work and distributing products among collective members. Furthermore, in the period of many political movements and class struggles, the identity of cadre could protect their families, relatives and themselves from being denounced and bullied (Tan, 1999).
At beginning, the commune itself was decorated as the representation of socialist society and had all merits of public ownership. Although nearly all the private property had been deprived, peasants had to praise the new system profusely. it was true, most poor peasants found that their lives changed, by eating in the public dining they didn’t need to worry about their own budget anymore, and by working together, they were not necessary to try their best. Following propaganda appeared in newspapers everyday:
The public dining halls are distributed in a way that members need walk only a few minutes from their homes to take their meals. On the freshly whitewashed walls of the one on Shihfuchien Street, a typical establishment, there is a big slogan in red, which reads, "High Spirits for Higher Production!" Its kitchen, to which the visitor is drawn by the aroma of food and the clatter of pots, is managed by Tu Hsiu-chen, the first volunteer cook, who has since learned large-scale catering from the chef at one of the city's restaurants.
The walls of the spacious dining room are decorated with paintings, as a home might be. Its tables and chairs, though simple, are scrubbed to a shining cleanliness. The food is fresh and tasty -- vegetables are grown by the commune itself. The staff make a special point of studying the diet and preferences of old people, children, nursing mothers and members with ailments. There is a separate room for parents with small children, provided with low tables for the little ones.( People’s Daily, 1958)
However, in practice, this ideal, extremely centralized form commune didn’t keep running well in most areas. Very soon it became clear that in most cases the communes were too clumsy to carry out successfully all the managerial and administrative functions that were assigned to them. The cooperative led to low-efficiency, the advantages of large-scale productivity didn’t arrive as peasants anticipated, productivity began to drop and discontent emerged. The reason lies in insufficient utilization of resources and lack of incentive of peasants. At one hand, the output of cooperation comes from all members’ work, in which the tribute of single household is difficult to be measured. So that opportunism like shirking happened naturally very frequently. An effective way to prevent shirking is to have all members supervised, but the seasonal work and spatial diversity of agricultural productive activities make it difficult to totally supervise. At the other hand, although brigade and production team cadres were obliged to complete state’s planning and all kinds of deliveries, the control right and residual claim of the people’s commune system were in the state’s hand, these cadres at grass-level could not design any reasonable incentive mechanism to encourage peasants to work hard and produce according to reasonable natural condition, such as soil, irrigation and farm year. The way left for brigade and team cadres was to punish peasants by struggling against them or maltreatment. But the brigade and team cadres also belonged to members of production teams, they and their families lived in the same community with their subordinates as well, so punishing peasants could also make themselves in trouble. Moreover, under the property rights structure of the commune system, the rest of output was not belong to the commune, brigade or even production team, but to the governments of higher level. This made the supervisors’ effort unrelated to any reward. As a result, even the supervisor himself has not enough incentive to work and shirk himself sometimes. In a word, under such conditions of poor supervision, in which all the work was distributed equally among all members at the lowest level--production team, shirking became every member’s rational choice and further weakening the efficiency of the system (Lin,1990).
De-collectivization
To prevent peasants from slow down, shrinking and escaping in work, and assure the system could keep on moving, the party collected all productive equipments and forbid members in people’s commune engaging in private production and business on the one hand, and at same time deprived peasants’ right of migrating from countryside to city or between districts by means of household registration on the other hand. Nevertheless, such policies had no effect on improving incentive of peasants, but they formed at least political press on very member of people’s commune, because it turned out that everyone’s only routine is to stay in the commune and finish one’s task. Without the right to leave or get better than others, peasants commonly chose to work with little effort, e.g. a passive method, to evade production tasks assigned by leader. Little accumulation and shirking made countryside widely fall into poverty , rare rural region had good conditions to develop industry or to improve commerce, infrastructures went worse, productivity sank quickly. The most serious crisis for agricultural collectivization happened between 1959 and 1961. GNP decreased from 213.8 billion Yuan in 1958 to 180.0 billion Yuan in 1962, with an average annual reduction of 15.1% in gross industrial production value and an average annual reduction of 19.3% in gross agricultural production value from 1958 to 1960. Owing to the serious shortage of food, a great famine took place in the whole country and at least 30 million residents died (Tan, 2000). Discontent with such system broke out, in some areas, peasants didn’t want to relied so heavily on orders from above and made so little allowance for local conditions or local initiative. The severe crisis forced the Party to adjust their policies. From 1961 on, commune functions were reduced to administration and co-ordination, production team was confirmed as the basic unit of accounting, certain production decision making was delegated to production teams, which were allowed to retain some income to overcome problems of egalitarianism; households again allowed to have small private plots and sidelines for planting vegetables, and a limited opening markets for transaction between urban and rural areas. However, these adjustments didn’t mean to change the system of people’s commune, but only to prevent peasants from rebel. From 1966 to 1976 China suffered the disaster of Cultural Revolution , there were large institutional swings took place in this period, in which co-operative moved from small to large and from team to brigade to commune again, local free markets, sidelines and private plots was prohibited again, and political factors had a great influence on production decisions.
In late 1970s, after the Leader Chairman Mao passed away, the requirement for improving agricultural productivity came alive. Administrators in provincial-level units with extensive regions of low yields and consequent low standards of living began experimenting with new forms of tenure and production. To avoid frontal conflicts of wide scope with government’s policies and the main ideology, a gradual approach was adopted. The first step of reform was to divide the production team into groups and to fix yield quotas for each group. Each group signed a contract with production team, the contractual items included the conditions of using land, laborers, farm tools and draft animals, the expenditure, labor contribution, rewards for excessive labor contribution and so on. After completing the tasks assigned by the production team, the output could be distributed among work groups according to their labor quotas. And then, the further solution was put forward, namely the typical form of fixing quotas called “all-round contract”, which was initiated by a few brave peasant secretly in Fengyang county of Anhui province. this contract regulated, household was allowed to cultivated a certain parcel farmland in the group, if grain quotas assigned by the state and the collective accumulation were accomplished, the household could own all the residual output. In the light of the contract, peasants were given directly stimulation to produce. The experiment was deemed successful and popular, and it soon spread to all districts.
At another side, political situation was appropriate with the reform form below. In the Eleventh National Party Congress, held August 12- 18, 1977 proclaimed the formal end of the Cultural Revolution, blamed it entirely on the Gang of Four , and reiterated that "the fundamental task of the party in the new historical period is to build China into a modern, powerful socialist country by the end of the twentieth century." The reformer Deng Xiaoping was elected as vice chairman and back to political stage and suggested a series of reform plans, though many contradictions still were apparent, change of policy was regarded as necessary. Rehabilitations of Deng's associates and others sympathetic to these reform plans were stepped up. Not only were some of those purged during the Cultural Revolution returned to power, but also individuals who had fallen from favor as early as the mid-1950s were rehabilitated. It was a time of increased political activism.
In November 1980, the Central Committee of Communist Party of China issued the document Some Issues of Further Reinforcing and Improving the Responsibility System in Agricultural Production. This article manifest the first time that the Party accepted the production responsibility systems developing in practice. In the document fixed output quotas of farmland for each group and responsibility contracts in some specialized obligations were indicated, at the same time, the fixed output quotas for household was also regarded as positive. Under the encouragement of government’s policy and related support measures, plenty of production responsibility systems developed very rapidly in rural areas. In 1981, a wide deeper reform called fixing the contribute quote for each household (bao gan dao hu), which was much more radical, was implemented. In accordance to the system, all collective lands in production teams were to be distributed among households based on their population or laborers. The households could manage the lands, made production decisions by themselves, and bore the results. When tasks assigned by upper government and the collective accumulation, e.g. a certain quantity of grain and livestock, were completed, the remained products could be owned by the households and not distributed among members in the production team. Moreover, if the household made sure that they have enough ration, they had right to sell the left grain to state owned agricultural enterprises or consume them as they want, usually feeding livestock or making wine for example. That meant the model from Fengyang was finally admitted by Party. In October 1983, the Party and the State Counsel issued the document Notice of Separating the Co-operative from Politics and Setting Up the Township Government and required the cooperative to separate from local government. The act ordered that the people's communes were replaced by administrative townships. By the end of 1984, 98% of production teams had taken the reform of Household Responsibility System. It was until then, the collectivization system was dismantled completely.
Some Characters of De-collectivization and Problems left
No restitution
Yet, de-collectivization and the implement of the household responsibility system is neither a reform of the ownership of land nor a process of privatization. As we have mentioned above, after the Communist Party set up its own government in 1949, it started land reform and distributed lands to the poor from landlords and rich peasants. Peasant acquired parcels of land according to the labor forces, then land were registered under name of each household. Before the eve of collectivization, most of lands in rural China were legally privately owned. But when de-collectivization began, peasants did not get back their former lands again. The household responsibility system only distribute the right of manage and benefit of lands among households according to their population or laborers. So, the de-collectivization in China did not like that in most of East European countries such as Bulgaria, Czech, Hungary, Poland, Romania and Slovakia, but like that in Albania. That is to say, there was no restitution of land. However, in former East European Countries, whether restitution was implemented or not, the de-collectivization had symbiosis with privatization. In China, although during the process of de-collectivization there were in reality some opinions that lands should be restituted, such voices were not accepted, nor even discussed.
The reasons why restitution of land in the de-collectivization of rural China did not happen may lie in some historic reasons. First of all, although peasants in China had private ownership over lands before the collectivization, large percent of peasants owned farmlands that did not belong to them before, they obtain them from political transformation. Theoretically, violence can’t consist the legal reason of transfer of ownership over real estate, therefore even after the terrorize during the land reform at beginning of 1950s, the private ownership of lands, which was made out by the communist government, had not yet became stable and commonly accepted. However, the former landlord class had rooted off during the political movement, land contacts and register books of land title had been destroyed, no one dare to challenge the power of Communist Party anymore. Since the collectivization began soon after the land reform, the new established owner relationship was broken again, when de-collectivization came about, without supports from the central government, most of peasants only took the household responsibility system as another chance of equally distributing lands, just like the land reform in 1949. As to descendants of former landlord class, they might have not forgotten the experience of their poor ancestors’: claiming private right before the Party which regarding public ownership as universal truth is a dangerous deal.
Secondly, different from most country in former communist east European countries , in which farmers’ nominal ownership of lands was remained, even though their lands were requisitioned in collective farms without any payment, and so that it was easy for peasants in these countries to take back the land when the collective farms went over. On the contrary, in China, private ownership of land was totally abolished as soon as the people’s commune system was set up, after 20 years, the collective ownership had already fest basis. As a result, the transaction costs of restitution so high as to wipe it out. That means, even a peasant want to take back the former farmland which belonged to them, it’s very hard to him to collect the relevant evidences to support his claim, moreover, there was no legal justice process to support such application. So normal farmer would rather to accept the Household Responsibility System.
Finally, the key reason lies in the socialism system itself. Even though the Communist Party of had poor performance in leading the country and its people to wealth and happiness during socialist revolution, Chinese people have taken socialism as the characteristic of the country for grant, after all the slogan “ Socialism saved China” has been deeply impressed. So that even after the Culture Revolution, most people still propped up the Party. The Party led the rural reform and decided the de-collectivization. However, the reform is a “liberation of the rural productivity”, which suit the requirement of the Party. Because the Chinese Communist Party insisted that his mission is to realize socialism, and socialism is based on public ownership system. Collective ownership was deemed as one form of public ownership in rural regions, so that as China kept on the road of realizing socialism, “land in rural areas belong to collective” was certainly remained after rural reform, and regulated in the Constitution of 1982, which is valid till now.
At the time of de-collectivization, the dissolution of people’s commune and the wide implement of responsibility system were regard as a great innovation. According to the statistic, The Household Responsibility System did bring about a more prosperous agriculture in China. From 1978 to 1984, grain output in China increased at an annual average rate of 5% and the gross value of agriculture by 7.7% (Lin, 1997). In contrast with former European countries, the de-collectivization seems bring more benefit to Chinese peasants at beginning. So that at that time, rare peasant did realize that such a reform without transformation of ownership was incompletely. However, The natural shortcomings of the de-collectivization would surely bring a series of problems.
institutional problem: land distribution
As we showed above, the de-collectivization ran smoothly and the introduction of Household Responsibility System has got a great success, although it could not address everything as only an institutional innovation. After several years of practice, it has been already proved that there are a number of weaknesses and limitations remained from the incompletely de-collectivization. One has to confirm, that the collective ownership and contract system led to the inequity in both economic and political features.
In economic view, during the de-collectivization, farmland was distributed to individual households in form of fragmented farming units. The principle of land distribution was derived directly from collective ownership. Farmland in a village was owned by all of its members collectively. As a result, every member had equal right to claim on distribution of the land according to certain norm, which was based primarily on the size of the peasant family. In reality of China with abundant population and limited land, the amount can be distributed to each household was very small. Moreover, land differed from each other in terms of soil fertility, irrigation conditions, location and so on. In many cases, a household had to obtain pieces of land from each of the grades. as a result, the sum was not only insufficient but also disjointed and scattered around villages. Large areas of cultivated land were wasted in the form of paths and boundaries separating households' contract field. A survey conducted by the Chinese Ministry of Agriculture indicated that in 1986, among 7983 sample villages from 29 provinces, average cultivated area per household was 0.466 ha (7 mu) fragmented into 5.85 plots, each plot on average 0.08 ha (1.2 mu) (Ministry of Agriculture of China, 1993) . This fragmented structure of family farming has remained largely untouched after implement of contract system and has detained the possibilities of using relatively advanced mechanical agricultural equipment and infrastructures.
Under such system, farmers turned to be short-term in action. According to the distribute rule of land in household responsibility system, land is to distribute depended only on villager status, babies and villagers' new-comer such as newly married bride from other villages were all eligible claimants, which having equal rights to share equal amounts of land in this village; on the contrary, when a villager left or died, the right of land claim would automatically withdraw. As population increased, villages had to readjust the distribution structure, which further subdivided the farmland . The endless redistribution of farmland resulted in many problems, including: 1) the situation of a small and fragmented farming structure further deteriorated; 2) worrying about the risk of losing their land as well as investment, farmers had little incentives to improve land conservation and agricultural infrastructure - irrigated land, one of the most significant components of agricultural infrastructure in China, remained almost unchanged during the 1980s; 3) farmers over-exploited the soil to pursue short-term profits; 4) the course of land redistribution was also costly, it required labor and time in organization and execution. (Chen, 1999)
Another problem is that farmland was generally badly endowed with the appropriate human capital. Since egalitarianism was the general leading principle rule, which gave little consideration to interfamily differences such as labor capability, education and individual preference . As a result, some large households with a incomplete labor force could have comparably much more land to cultivate, meanwhile other smaller households, above all those specialized in agriculture, could have only inadequate land for full employment. Such kind of problem was much worse in rural areas experiencing rapid township or village industry and urbanization. In those region there was often deterioration in the agricultural labor force since most of capable labors tended not to work at home as a farmer. There were many who did not give priority to cultivation and at times even let the land lie unused. Consequently, the farmland was underutilized .
Upon preceding analyzing, we can see that, in order to pursue egalitarianism on surface in distribution of land, in the process of the de-collectivization sacrificed economic efficiency. Thus, if the land was private, then those difference arouse from distribution will decease after enough time, because the free market will lead to equal efficiency through the choose of market. However, such political background lacked from beginning on, so that the shortcoming of a non-privatization de-collectivization can’t be corrected or even be enlarged because of problem of political system.
One of the main reason is political structure over the collective ownership. First at grass-root level, it was usually the village head, who takes the power to decide distribution since decentralization. So that the cadre family or their relations will surely benefit from the distribution. Having a cadre in the family seems to be a certain prerogative in using their political status to accumulate wealth. At one hand, Village cadres may allocate more fertile parts of the village land to themselves and determined more favorable grain sales quotas for themselves. And also, cadres have more opportunity to build personal relationship with higher level and other important departments, rural credit banks or transportation companies for example, so that they have more chance to obtain material benefit than normal peasants. As we see, most of collective enterprises and private economies in rural areas have tight relationship with local governments, at the basic level, with villager cadres, most rural enterprisers are villager leader themselves. Furthermore, cadres and their relations generally tend to break the policy of birth control, because they are capable to support more family members, and their kin will strengthen their economic and political power in return.
At another hand, though according to the election regulation of rural cadre in china, these village cadre should be elected directly by villagers, who have common interest in the community, this rule has been almost never put into practice. Under one Party system and public ownership system, all important resources are gathered in the Party’s hand, as a result, instead of election, the opinion from higher level plays a significant role, in order to carry ort the policy of Party efficiently. In fact, two factors determine the candidates in appointment of village head, one is the relationship with official of higher level, and the other is kinship. Consequently, cadre family takes all advantages to maintain their power and status through such appointment. So, cadres in rural China don’t represent the benefit of their village members, but the power of the Party as well as the family, there is no possibility for peasants to claim equality or save their from suffering as a peasant.
In a word, after a short flourish in rural China, which came along with the de-collectivization and the implement of Household Responsibility System, most peasants have to face the irrational occupation and distribution system of farmland and the political system, which is impossible to change. Besides there was strict limitation prevent peasants from abandoning their responsible land and rushing into cities, so that the peasants found it is hard to change their situation or turn it more better and free. This may explain why in rural china exists always the tendency of over population but the income of household began to decrease only after less than 10 years from the de-collectivization. As a result, land reform in China has emerged as a difficult issue in rural areas of exchange between social equality and economic efficiency. It seems obvious that since the mid-1980s the wide rural society has been caught in this predicament: where social equality or equity worsened, and at same time economic efficiency held back.. According to statistics, average net income in countryside has been slowed down for years. In 2000, the household average income only reached 272 dollars, but the Gini coefficient in China base in urban and rural areas rose from 0.21 in 1978 to more than 0. 46.

深圳经济特区商品房产管理规定

广东省人大常委会


深圳经济特区商品房产管理规定
广东省人大常委会



(1983年11月15日广东省第六届人民代表大会常务委员会第四次会议通过)

目 录

第一章 总 则
第二章 房产预售(预购)
第三章 房产权转移
第四章 房产抵押
第五章 房屋租赁
第六章 房产登记
第七章 罚 则
第八章 附 则

第一章 总 则
第一条 为加强深圳经济特区商品房产的管理,保障房产经营者和房产主的合法权益,根据中华人民共和国有关法律、法令和《广东省经济特区条例》,特制定本规定。
第二条 本规定所称的商品房产,系指深圳市人民政府批准经营房产的国营企业和外国公民、华侨、港澳同胞、台湾同胞及其公司企业(以下简称客商)独资,或上述国营企业与客商合资、合作建筑的,用来进行买卖、出租的住宅、工商业楼宇、仓库、停车场及其他房屋。
本规定所称的房产权,系指房屋(上盖)所有权和该房屋所占用的土地使用权。
第三条 深圳市人民政府鼓励客商独资或与经深圳市人民政府批准经营房产的国营企业合资、合作,在深圳经济特区从事房产经营(即建筑、买卖、出租房屋等业务)活动;鼓励客商购置房产。
深圳市人民政府对在深圳经济特区购置住宅、别墅的外国公民、华侨、港澳同胞和台湾同胞,依照国家和广东省对深圳经济特区的有关规定,给予优惠待遇。
第四条 合资、合作经营房产的各方,应当根据平等互利和协商一致的原则,签订合资、合作经营房产合同。
第五条 独资经营的房产,房产权归独资经营者所有。
合资、合作经营的房产,房产权归合资、合作经营者共有。
自然人或法人购买的住宅、别墅和其他商品房产,房产权归购买者所有。
第六条 深圳市人民政府依法保护房产主的房产权,允许房产主通过房产买卖(包括预售、预购和拍卖)、赠与、交换、遗赠和继承等法律行为,将房产权转移给他人(自然人或法人);允许房产抵押和房屋租赁。
房产主有权对房产进行装修、维修,但改变房产结构、用途、外貌或扩建、拆建者,须经深圳市人民政府指定的部门批准。
第七条 深圳市人民政府根据深圳经济特区建设的需要,可以征用房产主的房产,并按照规定给予合理补偿和妥善安置。
第八条 房产经营、房产权转移、房产抵押和房屋租赁等,必须遵守中华人民共和国的法律和广东省经济特区的有关法规。
房产权转移、房产预售(预购)、房产抵押和房屋租赁合同的订立,应经深圳市公证处公证。
第九条 深圳市人民政府房产管理机关统一管理深圳经济特区商品房产,负责本规定的贯彻执行。

第二章 房产预售(预购)
第十条 房产经营者可以预售房产。预售房产必须具备下列条件:
(一)房产经营者领有《土地使用证》和《建筑许可证》;
(二)房屋建筑合同业已签订;
(三)在深圳市注册的银行开立代收房产预售款的专门账户;
(四)该期建筑预算总额的百分之二十已汇入深圳市开户银行。
共有房产的预售,必须有共有人的书面协议。
第十一条 房产预售(预购)必须签订房产买卖合同。合同内容由双方当事人协商拟定,但须写明:
(一)双方当事人姓名(或法人名称)、住址(或法人所在地);
(二)房产面积、座落(位置)和界线(并附图);
(三)土地使用的面积(份额)和年限;
(四)房产的用途;
(五)房产的价格;
(六)房产预售(预购)款交付办法;
(七)房产交付使用或预计交付使用日期;
(八)违约责任;
(九)合同纠纷的处理办法和受理机构名称;
(十)其他双方认为必要的事项。
第十二条 房产预购人必须将房产预购款,存入房产经营者按照本规定第十条第一款第三项开立的银行专门账户。
房产预售款必须用于已预售的房屋建筑。
共有房产预售款的支取,必须由共有人会签或由共同指定的代理人代签。
第十三条 房产经营者领到房屋建筑竣工证后,应及时书面通知房产预购人,并向深圳市人民政府房产管理机关声请办理房产权转移登记手续。

第三章 房产权转移
第十四条 房产买卖必须按照本规定第十一条由双方当事人签订房产买卖合同。
房产主将其房产赠与他人,应当和受赠人签订房产赠与合同。
第十五条 共有房产的买卖、交换,须经房产共有人的一致同意,订有书面协议。房产共有人对一致同意的共有房产的买卖、交换负有连带责任。
书面协议无法成立时,房产共有人得将属于自己份额的房产进行买卖、交换。
房产共有人将自己份额的房产出售时,在同等条件下,其他共有人有优先购买权。
第十六条 房产共有人之一将属于自己份额的房产赠与或遗赠他人,可以不经其他共有人同意。
共有房产的继承亦同。
第十七条 按照本规定第十五条第二款和第十六条进行房产权转移之前,房产共有人必须进行共有房产的分割,并订立分割房产合同。

第四章 房产抵押
第十八条 房产主申请房产抵押贷款,必须向设在深圳经济特区的银行办理,并具备下列条件:
(一)房产买卖合同业已订立;
(二)领得《房产权证书》。
第十九条 房产抵押,必须订立房产抵押合同。合同内容由双方当事人协商拟定,但须写明:
(一)抵押人姓名(名称)和承押人的名称;
(二)房产名称、面积、座落(位置)和界线(并附图);
(三)抵押贷款数额和付款办法;
(四)抵押贷款的利率;
(五)抵押人偿还贷款的时间和数额;
(六)抵押人造成抵押房产损毁时应负的赔偿责任;
(七)违约责任;
(八)合同纠纷的处理办法和受理机构名称;
(九)其他双方认为必要的事项。
承押人可委托深圳市法律顾问处代理签订房产抵押合同,但须出具委托代理书。
第二十条 预售(预购)房产的抵押,按以下程序进行:
(一)抵押人和承押人签订房产抵押合同;
(二)抵押人持房产抵押合同至深圳市人民政府房产管理机关领取《房产权证书》;
(三)抵押人将《房产权证书》交承押人收存,承押人按房产抵押合同的规定付款。
第二十一条 抵押人不依照房产抵押合同规定偿还贷款,承押人有权拍卖抵押的房产。
第二十二条 承押人拍卖抵押的房产前,须通知抵押人并限定搬迁日期。其限期自抵押人接到通知之日起计算,不得少于三十天。
抵押人逾期不迁出,承押人或其代理人可按《中华人民共和国民事诉讼法(试行)》的规定,向人民法院申请执行;承押人因此所受的损失由抵押人赔偿。
第二十三条 抵押人如将抵押的房产租给他人,应征得承押人同意。
第二十四条 抵押房产的拍卖,应委托深圳市物业管理公司代理,由承押人与深圳市物业管理公司订立委托拍卖房产合同。
第二十五条 承押人拍卖抵押房产所得的价款,按以下顺序使用:
(一)偿付因拍卖抵押房产而支出的一切费用;
(二)扣缴所欠税款;
(三)扣还抵押人所欠的贷款及应付的利息;
(四)扣除上述三项款额后,如有余款,承押人应将余款交付抵押人。
拍卖房产所得价款如不敷偿还,承押人有权另行追索。
第二十六条 共有房产的抵押,比照本规定第十五条执行。

第五章 房屋租赁
第二十七条 房屋租赁(包括转租)必须签订房屋租赁合同。合同内容由双方当事人协商拟定,但须包括:
(一)房屋的座落(位置)、面积、装饰、设备;
(二)房屋的用途;
(三)租赁期限(定期或不定期);
(四)租金数额和交纳办法;
(五)提前解除合同的条件和应负的责任;
(六)违约责任;
(七)其他双方认为必要的事项。
第二十八条 房屋租赁期限,不得超过该房屋的土地使用期限。
第二十九条 房产共有人对房屋租赁合同的签订、解除、续订和承租人的转租,必须协商一致,订有书面协议,并负有连带责任。
房产共有人之一将属于自己份额的房产出租,比照本规定第十七条执行。
第三十条 房屋承租人可以将所租入的房屋转租他人,但须征得房产主同意。
房屋转租的租期,不得超过原租约的租期。
第三十一条 有下列情形之一者,出租人可以提前解除房屋租赁合同:
(一)出租人因不可预见的原因,确有需要使用该房屋的;
(二)承租人违反合同改变房屋用途的;
(三)承租人不按合同规定的期限缴纳房租,迟延时间超过三个月(包括三个月)的;
(四)承租人违反本规定第三十条的;
(五)承租人损坏房屋或设备而不维修、不赔偿的;
(六)房屋发生重大损坏,有倾倒危险而须改建,并确有证明的。
第三十二条 有下列情形之一者,承租人可以提前解除房屋租赁合同:
(一)承租人已建有或购有房屋,无需继续租赁他人房屋的;
(二)承租人举家迁离深圳市居住的;
(三)房屋发生重大损坏,有倾倒危险,而出租人不进行修缮的。
第三十三条 出租人按照本规定第三十一条第一项收回房屋的,或者按第六项收回房屋,而无正当理由在三个月内未动工改建的,应赔偿承租人因迁让所受的损失。
承租人按照本规定第三十二条第一项、第二项,提前解除房屋租赁合同,应赔偿出租人因此所受的损失。
第三十四条 按照本规定第三十一条第六项收回改建后的房屋,仍出租时,原承租人有优先承租权。
第三十五条 承租人依约缴纳房租,出租人无正当理由而拒绝收受时,承租人可向深圳市公证处申请给予证明,以免除其迟延责任。
因进行前款规定的公证而支出的费用,从房租中扣除。
第三十六条 出租房屋的修缮,由出租人负担;如因承租人的故意或过失造成损失的,由承租人负担。
第三十七条 房屋租赁当事人一方要解除合同时,须提前书面通知对方。民用房屋租赁,定期的提前一个月;不定期的提前两个月。工商业房屋租赁,一律提前六个月。
租赁合同解除后,如承租人逾期不迁出,出租人可按《中华人民共和国民事诉讼法(试行)》的规定,向人民法院申请执行;出租人因此所受的损失由承租人负责赔偿。
第三十八条 房屋出租,不妨碍房产权转移。
房产权转移后,房屋租赁合同继续生效,新、旧房产主应联名以书面通知承租人。
租赁房屋出售时,承租人在同等条件下有优先购买权。

第六章 房产登记
第三十九条 商品房产的房产主或权利人,须按下列规定,向深圳市人民政府房产管理机关进行房产登记:
(一)确定产权登记:声请确定房产权,领取《房产权证书》,由房产主办理登记。
(二)转移登记:房产权转移者,除遗赠、继承登记可由受赠人或继承人取具证明单独办理外,均由当事人双方进行登记。
(三)变更登记:房产权因房屋扩建、改建、拆除、分割、合并等而变更,由房产主声请登记,其变更涉及其他关系人者,须会同关系人办理。
(四)他项权利登记:房产设定优惠权、抵押权、地役权(通行权)等项权利的登记,由权利人会同义务人声请登记。
(五)更正登记:因现持《房产权证书》与实际情况不符,或因迁移地址、更换门牌等有更正必要的,由房产主或权利人声请登记。
(六)注销登记:房产权因房产被自然灾害破坏或被拆除而消失,他项权利因约定时效届满而消失,均由房产主或权利人和关系人声请注销登记。
第四十条 房产登记,须缴验下列证件:
(一)声请登记书;
(二)声请人的身份证明文件;
(三)取得、变更、转移房产权的全部证件。
共有房产的房产权登记,可由房产共有人之一进行,但须有其他共有人出具的委托书和有关的证明文件。
第四十一条 房产登记可委托代理。代理房产登记,除缴验本规定第四十条所列证件外,还须缴验经过公证的委托代理的证明文件。
声请者如系法人,由其代理人办理登记,但须缴验证明其法人代理人身份的文件。
第四十二条 房产主或权利人、关系人和代理人的居住地址如在香港、澳门、台湾省或外国,其缴验的房产登记证明文件,除经当地公证机构公证外,还应分别按照下列规定,办理认证手续:
(一)居住在香港、澳门的,通过深圳经济特区驻港代表机构办理认证。
(二)居住在台湾省的,凭本人身份证明,通过深圳经济特区驻港代表机构办理认证。
(三)居住在外国的,经我国驻该国大使(或领事)馆认证。
第四十三条 房产登记须缴纳登记费用。费用标准由深圳市人民政府房产管理机关制定。
房产登记由双方当事人会同声请者,费用由承受权利的一方缴纳。
第四十四条 房产主在房产登记后所领得的《房产权证书》,如有毁灭、遗失,应即向房产登记机关报告,并声请补发。
第四十五条 各项房产权利自取得之日起三个月内,权利人必须声请登记。超过半年不办理登记的房产,由深圳市人民政府房产管理机关代管;代管三年仍不办理登记者,视为无主房产,由房产管理机关提请司法机关依法处理。
第四十六条 商品房产所占用的土地使用期满,房产主应向深圳市人民政府申请延长土地使用期。超过半年不申请者,该房屋(上盖)比照本规定第四十五条处理。

第七章 罚 则
第四十七条 凡违反本规定所签订的合同,一律无效;由此而造成的损失,由违反者承担。
第四十八条 未经深圳市人民政府或其指定的机关批准,擅自改变房屋结构、用途、外貌或进行扩建、拆建者,除责令停止或恢复原貌外,并根据情节轻重,处以人民币五千元以下的罚款。
第四十九条 凡利用欺骗、冒名、伪造证件、行贿等非法手段进行房产登记的,除登记无效外,并根据情节轻重处以人民币二千元以上五千元以下的罚款;触犯《中华人民共和国刑法》,构成犯罪者,由司法机关依法追究直接责任人的刑事责任。
第五十条 对不按期进行房产权登记者,每逾期一日,应缴纳人民币一元以上五元以下的逾期金。
对土地使用期满不申请延长土地使用期者,按日加收滞纳土地使用费千分之一的滞纳金。

第八章 附 则
第五十一条 本规定所涉及的各项法律文件,如须中文和外文两种文字并列的,以中文为准。
第五十二条 本规定自公布之日起施行。



1983年11月22日